main

database-mathematics-solutions.com

On this website solutions of tasks in the general mathematics are collected.
Other databases:
  Subject
  All subjects  Calculus
  Econometric  Linear Algebra
  Numerical Analysis  Statistics
  Use search in keywords. (words through a space in any order)
   
  Only free   Search in found   Exact value

Online calculators
  About 3307 results. 1294 free access solutions
Page 158 from 166 Первая<148154155156157158159160161162166>
To the page  
 
 №  Condition free/or 0.5$
m83186The set of solutions to a system of linear inequalities Ax ≤ c is a convex set. buy
m83187The set S = {x1, x2, . . . , xn} is affinely dependent if and only if the set {x2 - x1, x3 - x1, . . . , xn - x1} is linearly dependent. Exercise 1.157 implies that the maximum number of affinely independent elements in an n dimensional space is n + 1. Moreover the maximum dimension of a proper affine subset is n. Analogous to exercise 1.133, we have the following alternative characterization of affine dependence. buy
m83188The set S = {x1. x2. . . . , xn} is affinely dependent if and only if there exist numbers a1, a2, . . . , an, not all zero, such that a1x1 + a2x2 +...........+ anxn = 0 with a1 + a2 +..........+ an = 0. Analogous to a basis, every vector in the affine hull of a set has a unique representation as an affine combination of the elements of the set. buy
m83191The space BL(X, Y) of all bounded linear functions from X to Y is a normed linear space, with norm It is a Banach space (complete normed linear space) if Y is complete. The following proposition is an important result regarding bounded linear functions. buy
m83194The system A is productive if and only if A-1 exists and is nonnegative. buy
m83211The unit simplex in ℜ buy
m83228There is no arbitrage if and only if there exist state prices. buy
m83239To construct a suitable space for the application of a separation argument, consider the set of points where eS is characteristic vector of the coalition S (example 3.19) and w(S) is its worth. Let A be the conic hull of A0, that is, Let B be the interval Clearly, A and B are convex and nonempty. We assume that the game is balanced and construct a payoff in the core. 1. Show that A and B are disjoint if the game is balanced. 2. Consequently there exists a hyperplane that separates A and B. That is, there exists a nonzero vector (z, z0) ∈ ℜn × ℜ such that for all y ∈ A and all ε > 0. Show that a. (e∅, 0) ∈ A implies that c = 0. b. (eN, w(N) ∈ A implies that z0 < 0. Without loss of generality, we can normalize so that z0 = -1. 3. Show that (36) implies that the payoff vector z satisfies the inequalities Therefore z belongs to the core. buy
m83240To prove corollary 2.4.1, let f: X → X be an increasing function on a complete lattice (X, ≿), and let E be the set of fixed points of f. For any S ⊆ E define S* = {x ∊ X : x ≿ s for every s ∊ S} S* is the set of all upper bounds of S in X. Show that 1. S* is a complete sublattice. 2. f (S*) ⊆ S*. 3. Let g be the restriction of f to the sublattice S*. g has a least fixed point . 4.  is the least upper bound of S in E. 5. E is a complete lattice. buy
m83241To prove corollary 2.4.2, let S c E and s* = sup S. 1. For every x ∊ S there exists some zx ∊ p(s*) such that zx ≿ x. 2. Let z* = sup zx. Then a. z* ≾ s* b. z* ∊ buy
m83242To prove lemma 1.1, assume, to the contrary, that for every c > 0 there exists x ∈ lin{x1; x2; . . . , xn} such that where x = a1x1 + a2x2 + • • • +‡anxn. Show that this implies that 1. There exists a sequence (x ) with |x ||→0 2. There exists a subsequence converging to some x ∈ lin {x1,x2,...xn} 3. x ≠ 0 contradicting the conclusion that ||x || → 0 This contradiction proves the existence of a constant c > 0 such that ||x|| ≥ c(|α1| + |α2| + ... +|αn|) for every x ∈ lin S. buy
m83243To show that each of the hypotheses of Brouwer s theorem is necessary, find examples of functions f : S → S with S ⊆ R that do not have fixed points, where 1. f is continuous and S is convex but not compact 2. f is continuous and S is compact but not convex 3. S is compact and convex but f is not continuous The following proposition, which is equivalent to Brouwer s theorem, asserts that it is impossible to map the unit ball continuously on to its boundary. buy
m83254Two inputs are said to complementary if their cross-partial derivative D2xixjf(x) is positive, since this means that increasing the quantity of one input increases the marginal productivity of the other. Show that if a production function of two inputs is linearly homogeneous and quasi concave, then the inputs are complementary. buy
m83256Two norms ||x||a and ||x||b on a linear space are equivalent if there are positive numbers A and B such that for all x ∈ X, The following exercise shows that there essentially only one finite dimensional normed linear space. buy
m83257Two players i and j are substitutes in a game (N, w) if their contributions to all coalitions are identical, that is, if W(S ∪ {i}) = w(S ∪ {j} for every S ⊆ N {i, j} Verify that the Shapley value treats substitutes symmetrically, that is i j substitutes ⇒ ϕiw = ϕjw buy
m83260Under what circumstances, if any, could the IS curve be horizontal? buy
m83261Union and intersection are one way of generating new sets from old. Another way of generating new sets is by welding together sets of disparate objects into another set called their product. The product of two sets X and Y is the set of ordered pairs X × Y = {(x, y): x ∈ X, y ∈ Y} A familiar example is the coordinate plane R × R which is denoted R2 (figure 1.2). This correspondence between points in the plane and ordered pairs x; y of real numbers is the foundation of analytic geometry. Notice how the order matters. (1, 2) and (2, 1) are different elements of R2. Figure 1.2 The coordinate plane R2 The product readily generalizes to many sets, so that X1 × X2 ×. . . . . . . .× Xn = {(x1, X2, . . . , xn} : xi ∈ Xi} is the set of all ordered lists of elements of Xi, and Rn = {(x1, X2, . . . , xn) : xi A Rg is the set of all ordered lists of n real numbers. An ordered list of n elements is called an n-tuple. Rn and its nonnegative subset Rn+ provide the domain of most economic quantities, such as commodity bundles and price lists. To remind ourselves when we are dealing with a product space, we will utilize boldface to distinguish the elements of a product space from the elements of the constituent sets, as in x = (x1, x2, . . . , xn) ∈ X where X = X1 × X2 ×. . . . . . . . . . . Xn. buy
m83342Use proposition 2.3 to provide an alternative proof of theorem 2.2 Theorem 2.2 A continuous functional on a compact set achieves a maximum and a minimum. Proof Let M = supx∊X f (x). There exists a sequence xn in X with f (xn) → M. Since X is compact, there exists a convergent subsequence xm → x* and f (xm) → M. However, since f is continuous, f (xm) → f (x*). We conclude that f (x*) = M. buy
m83343Use proposition 3.14 directly to prove the Farkas lemma when X is a Hilbert space. buy
m83363Use the Bolzano-Weierstrass theorem to show that R is complete. The following proposition is regarded as the most important theorem in topology. We give a simplified version for the product of two metric spaces. By induction, it generalizes to any finite product. In fact the theorem is also true of an infinite product of compact spaces. buy
 
Page 158 from 166 Первая<148154155156157158159160161162166>
To the page  
 

contacts: oneplus2014@gmail.com